Sunday, September 30, 2012
Friday, September 28, 2012
The Price of Fiscal Uncertainty
I have been reading Bob Woodward's new book, The Price of Politics. It is a detailed recounting of the back-and-forth negotiations among President Obama's White House, the Republican leaders in the House of Representatives, and the major players in the Senate regarding the debt ceiling and long-term fiscal outlook. The book is primarily an objective narrative, rather than a foaming-at-the-mouth polemic (unlike the over-the-top book The Amateur, which I read over the summer). Nonetheless, the story Woodward tells does not make this White House look particularly good.
Woodward seems to believe that if we had a President more like Bill Clinton, a fiscal deal could have been struck. President Obama is described as disdainful of schmoozing with other pols, as mishandling the negotiation process, and as unwilling to move sufficiently toward the political center to get a deal done. One gets the sense that the Democratic President who signed the 1996 welfare reform would have more easily reached a compromise with House Republicans.
This story brought to my mind recent research by Baker, Bloom, and Davis, which suggests that policy uncertainty has impeded the economic recovery. If Baker et al. are right that uncertainty depresses the economy, and if Woodward is right that the uncertainty we now face with the upcoming "fiscal cliff" is attributable mostly to the inability of Barack Obama to work with Congress, then the implication is clear: The meagerness of this recovery is not simply a hangover from a financial crisis, but rather a reflection of a fundamental political failure. The price of politics, indeed.
Woodward seems to believe that if we had a President more like Bill Clinton, a fiscal deal could have been struck. President Obama is described as disdainful of schmoozing with other pols, as mishandling the negotiation process, and as unwilling to move sufficiently toward the political center to get a deal done. One gets the sense that the Democratic President who signed the 1996 welfare reform would have more easily reached a compromise with House Republicans.
This story brought to my mind recent research by Baker, Bloom, and Davis, which suggests that policy uncertainty has impeded the economic recovery. If Baker et al. are right that uncertainty depresses the economy, and if Woodward is right that the uncertainty we now face with the upcoming "fiscal cliff" is attributable mostly to the inability of Barack Obama to work with Congress, then the implication is clear: The meagerness of this recovery is not simply a hangover from a financial crisis, but rather a reflection of a fundamental political failure. The price of politics, indeed.
Thursday, September 27, 2012
Wednesday, September 26, 2012
The Taxation of Capital Income
Many economists believe capital income should be taxed at a lower rate than labor income, perhaps even at a zero rate. Matthew Yglesias explains why.
Tuesday, September 25, 2012
Economics Teaching Conference
You can still register for the economics teaching conference on November 8 and 9 in Orlando, Florida. Early bird registration is open until October 10. Click here for more information.
FYI, I am among the keynote speakers.
FYI, I am among the keynote speakers.
Saturday, September 22, 2012
Mankiw vs. DeLong and Krugman on the CEA’s Real GDP Forecasts in Early 2009: What Might a Time Series Econometrician Have Said?
This post takes its title from a new article at Econ Journal Watch. Here is the abstract:
In early 2009, the incoming Obama administration’s Council of Economic Advisers predicted real GDP would rebound strongly from recession levels. In a blog post, Greg Mankiw expressed skepticism. In their blogs, Brad DeLong and Paul Krugman sighed. Of course there would be strong growth, they maintained, because the recovery of employment would mandate it via Okun’s Law. Mankiw challenged Krugman to a bet on the issue, but there was no response. Of course we now have a good idea of the likely outcome, but I posit a hypothetical time series econometrician who, at the time of the blog entries, applies some standard forecasting methods to see whether DeLong and Krugman’s confidence was justified. The econometrician’s conclusion is that Mankiw would likely win the bet and furthermore that a rebound of any significance is unlikely. The econometrician has no idea how DeLong and Krugman could have been so confident in the CEA’s rebound forecast.
In early 2009, the incoming Obama administration’s Council of Economic Advisers predicted real GDP would rebound strongly from recession levels. In a blog post, Greg Mankiw expressed skepticism. In their blogs, Brad DeLong and Paul Krugman sighed. Of course there would be strong growth, they maintained, because the recovery of employment would mandate it via Okun’s Law. Mankiw challenged Krugman to a bet on the issue, but there was no response. Of course we now have a good idea of the likely outcome, but I posit a hypothetical time series econometrician who, at the time of the blog entries, applies some standard forecasting methods to see whether DeLong and Krugman’s confidence was justified. The econometrician’s conclusion is that Mankiw would likely win the bet and furthermore that a rebound of any significance is unlikely. The econometrician has no idea how DeLong and Krugman could have been so confident in the CEA’s rebound forecast.
Wednesday, September 19, 2012
Saturday, September 15, 2012
A Break from Economics
My younger son and I attended a great concert last night by Florence + The Machine. If you aren't familiar with their music, here is a sample:
Thursday, September 13, 2012
The Trading Game
Duke economist Marc F. Bellemare has a cool in-class experiment to demonstrate the gains from trade.
Wednesday, September 12, 2012
A Reading for the Pigou Club
Here. A tidbit:
According to economists crunching the numbers, this makes mileage standards somewhere between 2.4 and 13 times more expensive than a gasoline tax as a tool to reduce our use of fuel. Indeed, by some calculations, raising fuel-economy standards is more costly than climate change itself.
Tuesday, September 11, 2012
Help Wanted
I am looking to hire a Harvard student to work with me as I revise my principles
textbook (along with several other less time-consuming tasks). The part-time job
requires strong writing/editing skills, the ability to proofread carefully, some
facility with data, and an interest in pedagogy. Work would start soon, and it
would continue throughout the academic year.
If you are interested, please drop off a brief letter, resume, and transcript with my assistant Lauren LaRosa in Littauer 236.
If you are interested, please drop off a brief letter, resume, and transcript with my assistant Lauren LaRosa in Littauer 236.
Friday, September 07, 2012
Harvey Rosen on the Romney Tax Plan
You can read what the Princeton public finance expert says at this link. Here is the bottom line:
I analyze the Romney proposal taking into account the additional income that might be generated by economic growth. The main conclusion is that under plausible assumptions, a proposal along the lines suggested by Governor Romney can both be revenue neutral and keep the net tax burden on high-income individuals about the same. That is, an increase in the tax burden on lower and middle income individuals is not required in order to make the overall plan revenue neutral.
Thursday, September 06, 2012
Wednesday, September 05, 2012
Ranking Universities
Last month, the Center for World-Class Universities at Shanghai Jiao Tong University released the 10th edition of its annual global university ranking. Click here to see the economics ranking.
Tuesday, September 04, 2012
An Article without a Single Wasted Word
Here is a paper I wish I had written,...I mean, not written.
Sunday, September 02, 2012
A Reply from Martin Feldstein
I am happy to lend this space to my Harvard colleague Martin Feldstein. -- Greg
Feasibility of the Romney
Tax Plan – Reply to Comments
Martin Feldstein
This note is a reply to those
who commented on my August 28 WSJ article (available here) about the Romney Tax Plan. The Romney income tax plan includes a 20% cut in all
individual tax rates, eliminating the AMT, and eliminating the taxes on
interest, dividends and capital gains for those with incomes under $100,000. The resulting revenue loss is balanced in the
plan by broadening the tax base for high-income taxpayers.
The Tax Policy Center (and
others citing their report) claimed that the Romney plan is “mathematically
impossible” and that the plan would inevitably lead to a large middle class tax
increase or a rise in the budget deficit.
I found that that conclusion is
not correct. It is possible to cut taxes as Gov. Romney indicates and to
finance it with base broadening for taxpayers with AGI over $100,000. Governor
Romney has not specified the base broadening that he would propose. My
calculations presented here and in the WSJ are not estimates of the Romney plan
but an indication that such a plan is feasible.
For the WSJ article I analyzed the most recent
published IRS data (for 2009). The cost
of the Romney proposed tax cuts would be $219 billion in that year with no
behavioral response (the “static estimate”) or $186 after a $33 billion
reduction in cost caused by the behavioral response to lower marginal rates
(with an elasticity of the tax base with respect to the net-of-tax share of 0.5.)
Those IRS data also implied that
eliminating all deductions for taxpayers with AGI above $100,000 would increase
the tax base by $636 billion. I
multiplied the $636 billion by a 30 percent marginal tax rate for the
high-income taxpayers, implying $191 billion of extra revenue. That would be
enough to finance the $186 billion revenue loss. All taxpayers with AGI below $100,000 would
have tax cuts and no tax increase. I concluded that even without further base
broadening the plan is feasible and would not involve either a middle class tax
increase or a rise in the budget deficit.
The critics of my WSJ piece
raised 4 objections: (1) The 30 percent marginal tax rate is too high for these
taxpayers because of the 20% Romney rate reduction. (2) The behavioral response
(reducing the cost of rate reduction by $33 billion) is too large because the
elasticity of the tax base would be lower than the 0.5 I assumed. (3) Applying
the base broadening to those with incomes above $100,000 would create a “notch”
with a jump in tax liabilities near that level. (4) The Tax Policy Center
defined the middle class as all taxpayers with incomes under $200,000 while I
used $100,000.
While I still believe the assumptions
that I used in my analysis, I can modify them as suggested by the critics and
still support my original conclusion by broadening the tax base in ways
suggested but not developed in my WSJ piece. Eliminating a few of the “tax
expenditure” exclusions and credits that are important for high-income
taxpayers would raise more than enough revenue to compensate for assuming a
smaller marginal tax rate, cutting the behavioral response effect in half, and
phasing in the base broadening for individuals with incomes over $100,000 to
avoid the notch.
More specifically, using a
25% marginal tax rate instead of 30% would reduce the revenue from eliminating
deductions by 5% of $636 billion or $32 billion. Cutting the behavioral response in half
(i.e., using a taxable income elasticity of just 0.25) would raise the cost of
the tax cut by $17 billion. The cost of
the “phase in” would depend on just how it was done but say another $15 billion
of reduced revenue. So instead of my
conclusion that the revenue from eliminating deductions would exceed the cost
of the tax cuts by $5 billion, these assumptions would imply a shortfall to be
made up by other base broadening of $64 billion.
One part of that broadening
could be eliminating the exclusion of employer payments for health insurance
for those with AGI over $100,000. That would increase income tax revenue by about $40
billion (out of the total revenue loss from the health insurance exclusion for
all taxpayers of $168 billion) plus an
additional $10 billion of additional payroll tax revenue. (My estimate of this $40
billion is based on an imputation method developed by John Gruber based on data
collected in the Medical Expenditure Panel Study.)
Eliminating the exclusion of
municipal bond interest for taxpayers with AGI over $100,000 would increase tax
revenue by an additional $15 billion.
Eliminating the child credit
for those with incomes over $100,000 would increase revenue by an additional
$10 billion.
So just those three changes to
the list of base broadening measures would raise $75 billion or more than
enough to exceed the $64 billion of potential shortfall with the very
conservative assumptions noted above.
Additional tax revenue could
be raised without reducing incentives to save or to invest efficiently by eliminating
the exclusion for high-income taxpayers of such things as capital gains on home
sales, the “cafeteria plan” benefits, and the capital gains at death.
One further point on the
appropriate marginal tax rate (objection 1 above): although the top statutory
rate is 35 percent, the effective top marginal tax rate is higher because of
various phase-out provisions that affect high-income taxpayers (PEP, Pease,
etc.) so my original assumption of a 30 percent marginal tax rate could be
appropriate even with the Romney rate reductions.
The final objection is to my
use of the $100,000 level to show that the middle class (i.e., those below
$100,000 AGI) would experience no tax increases. The $100,000 level corresponds
to 21 percent of all taxable returns and a significantly smaller fraction of
all households. I think it is very
reasonable to say that people in that high-income group are not the “middle
class.” The TPC focus on those with AGI over $200,000 limits that group to the
top 4 million taxpayers who are three percent of all returns and five percent
of all taxable returns.
So I think my conclusion
stands: it is feasible to combine tax cuts and base broadening as Governor
Romney suggests without raising the budget deficit or imposing any middle class
tax increase. Critics might not like the Romney plan but they cannot call it
“mathematically impossible.”